- Posts: 2143
- Joined: Tue Aug 28, 2012 5:32 am
Now, your statement above is weird. Of course objective criteria are involved in what people are willing to pay for Apple computers. What the computers can objectively do, as opposed to what their competitors can objectively do, does factor into what people are willing to pay. So, the value of Apple computers is not just based on its aggregate demand, which is a theoretical concept to begin with. So, not only can we not actually establish the aggregated demand for a particular player, since not all players will be voting, the aggregate demand is not the only factor determining a SOM card's value. Objective criteria do apply.franky35 wrote:In general, I am arguing for free market principles. We know how much Apple Computer is worth not because of any objective criteria but because of what people are willing to pay to own Apple Computer. That is, the value of Apple computer is based on it's aggregate demand. Likewise, we can measure the value of strat players based on the aggregate demand for a given card.
Also, as I pointed out earlier, re-pricing based on demand/usage will just replicate current problems. Since many overused players are only used because of their low price. Once their prices are raised, they will go unused, need to be re-priced, and we'll be right back where we were before.
This statement must be wrong. If Singleton's price were raised by 0.5 mil, he would still be used but he would be used less often. If the price of Ken Singleton were raised and the price of Briggs were lowered, the demand for Singleton would decrease and the demand for Briggs would increase. When the prices are set such that the demand for Singleton = the demand for Briggs, then the price is set fairly according to the market. Since we know that, at the current prices, there is more demand for Singleton than Briggs, we know that repricing will not result in getting back to the current prices but will result in the price for Singleton going up relative to the current price for Briggs.
My statement was absolutely correct; so your statement must be wrong and is. First of all, if you read my earlier posts, you would know I wasn't talking about players like Briggs and Singleton when I said "over-used" players. So, try to read better. Over-used players are those who are only used because of their particularly low price. Thus, their over-use will lead to over-pricing, which will lead to under-usage. So we will be right back where we were before, and your Briggs anecdote is irrelevant and doesn't apply.
IMO, if owners continually compete over certain players and ignore other players, then it must be that certain players are subjectively underpriced and others are subjectively overpriced.
This isn't true. You neglect the fact the pricings were based on objective statistics. So, while subjective opinions were a factor in them, they were not entirely subjective pricings.
The above statement is just weird. I argued that certain players are subjectively underpriced and you responded that wasn't true because the pricings were based on objective statistics. Your statement only makes sense if you replace the word "subjectively" with the word "objectively", and that is such a weird way of arguing that I can't grasp it.
My above statement was clear and sound. You just didn't read it well...again. I said clearly that the pricings were based on both subjective opinion and objective statistics. Therefore the players weren't just subjectively underpriced and subjectively overpriced as you said. I didn't have to replace any words. If you can't grasp that clear syllogistic logic and grammar, you have my sympathies.
You also need to amend your erroneous notions of "objective" and "subjective." Since objective facts and statistics were involved in SOM's pricings, they weren't just subjective and your claim they were was incorrect. You made the same error in your Apple Computer argument and need to realize full objectivity and full subjectivity rarely occur.
Actually, I don't think that at all. I think that since Briggs is almost never selected, he has an overpriced card. As the cost of his card is reduced, the demand for his card will increase. This correlation is true for almost all products and services except for the class of products and services that are termed "inelastic" (an example of an inelastic good is cancer treatment - healthy people won't take it for free but people who need it will pay almost any price). It is true that different owners think differently. If Briggs' cost were cut in half, I would not select him, but I think such a price cut would make him attractive to other owners. The concept of "equal aggregate demand" does not mean that all owners think identically but it means that the total demand summed over all owners is equal between any two selected players.Your prediction all players will move toward a system where all players have an "equal aggregate demand" incorrectly presumes all players will think in the same way and move in the same direction. They don't do so now, and they won't in the future. That applies to your Briggs analogy. Since all players still won't view Briggs in the same way--we do think differently--what you describe won't occur.
Yes, you do "think that at all." Your notion of an inevitable movement towards an "equal aggregate demand" does presume everyone will think and value in a particular way. You affirm that with your own paragraph above, assuming everybody will re-evaluate Briggs in a similar way. Yes "equal aggregate demand" refers to the equal demand for two players, but you are still erroneously assuming they will move towards it.
Also, you can't use the same economic theories referring to ever-fluctuating price structures with static price structures. Even if SOM re-prices yearly, it's prices will still remain static for a year, so your usage of those theories isn't applicable.
To stick with the 70s, this describes our current system. At least on the hitter's side, most of the fan favorites are priced artificially low. In every single league, Stargell, Schmidt, Brett, Bench, are on somebody's team at the start of the season. If these stars were priced according to demand, they would cost more until they would be equally attractive (in the aggregate) to Andre Thornton (or Thornton would cost less). But I'm ok with this pricing because I'm a baseball fan and it is more fun for me to manage Pops instead of Thornton.Why would we want a system where the star players are priced artificially low?
I'm a baseball fan, too, as are many others who don't want their leagues to be full of super-teams. That's why we have 100,000 and above leagues that aren't normal. So, your desire is a particularly subjective one that most don't want. And most of the 70's stars are not priced ridiculously low. Even if it was, it wouldn't add any logic to your desire.
Again, here you misunderstand the term "aggregate demand." This term means the total demand summed over all individuals and does not mean that all individuals have the same preferences.all managers don't think alike and will not move towards the collective of "aggregate demand" you said they would.
As I showed above, I don't misunderstand the term at all. You just misunderstood my statement. Even if "aggregate demand" refers to a particular demand, you still erroneously assume all the players are going to move towards the particular "aggregate demand" you claim. That was what I was correctly criticizing.